loader image

Volatility returns to emerging markets

By Economic Strategist, Hottinger Investment Management  

A few years ago, the management consulting firm McKinsey produced a striking graphic. It showed how the economic centre of gravity has shifted over the millennia. In AD 1, the place to be was Asia. China and India produced about 70% of world GDP, with the rest shared by the Ancient world (Greece, Egypt, Turkey and Iran), Europe and Africa. That centre of gravity only really started to move in the 1500s, after the Black Death had transformed Europe’s social and economic institutions. By WW2 it was at its most westerly point, between Western Europe and the United States, as those two places accounted for 70% of world GDP. By 2025, McKinsey expects the world to be back to where it was in AD 1.

China and India will soon again account for the lion’s share of the world economy as the trend for countries with large, well-educated populations with strong governance systems to dominate takes hold. The French essayist Paul Valery was probably the first to notice this trend, writing in the aftermath of the first world war:

“So, the classification of the habitable regions of the world is becoming one in which gross material size, mere statistics and figures (e.g., population, area, raw materials) finally and alone determine the rating of the various sections of the globe.”

In the coming decades, it will make sense from an investment point of view to have an Asia-first focus, with the deliberations of the Central Bank of India and the People’s Bank of China carrying the weight that the decisions of the Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank have today. The International Monetary Fund predicts that in the next few years at least the continent of Asia will grow at 5.5% per year and account for two-thirds of all the world’s growth. By contrast, the U.S and Europe will struggle to grow faster than 2.5% per year.

It is in this context that we should see the rise in volatility in emerging markets in the last few months (see chart below). Over the last five years, there has been remarkable convergence between market volatility in the G7 and that in the emerging markets. Usually, emerging markets are attractive for investors who have long time horizons and a preference for growth over income in their portfolios, but in 2016 and 2017, according to the JP Morgan indices for volatility, emerging markets had as much average risk as that in G7 countries.

This year, emerging market volatility has risen sharply. Some of it is on the back of concerns over the fiscal sustainability of particular countries such as Turkey and Argentina; both of these countries have low levels of foreign reserves to support public debt in the event that tax revenues come up short. Similar to the situation in the United States, there is concern about over-leverage in corporate debt in some developing countries.

But much of the explanation lies with what developed-market central banks are doing with their monetary policies. The Federal Reserve has raised rates significantly in the last year, and have the intention to continue increasing rates until 2020. It is also selling Treasury bonds that it holds on its balance sheet at the time when the Trump Administration is planning to run $1trn annual budget deficits, funded by sales of new bonds to the public. With US interest rates still seen as a benchmark for the global economy, all these developments mean that global yields are rising on government and corporate bonds; additionally, the supply of dollars is more limited, strengthening the dollar exchange rate and making it harder for emerging markets to service their dollar debts.

This latter explanation reflects emerging markets’ vulnerability to external factors more than fundamental unsoundness with the direction of economic policy and development. It is why in the medium-run we should still expect relatively higher volatility to be the price to pay for exposure to developing countries, and why–although we should be concerned with the big uptick in EM volatility–we should place it in its proper perspective. As emerging economies grow, they will develop policy independence and less sensitivity to global events.

Political risk returns to Europe as the ECB tightens

It has been an eventful few weeks in Europe. Markets have been actively following the unfolding situation in Italy, as the new 5 Star-Lega coalition of populist parties took office. Things have quietened down as the members of the new government have reassured investors that it has no intention of leaving the euro, or breaking EU-mandated public spending limits that might have led to the same event.

But this is not the end of the story because there are a range of possible events stemming from Italy that could unnerve markets in the coming months and test the political foundations of the eurozone.

The bold macroeconomic policies of the new Italian government are the central issue, and will create headaches in Europe. The recently agreed 5 Star-Lega populist administration has plans to sharply increase benefits to the unemployed, radically cut taxes, reduce the retirement age, and increase infrastructure spending. Independent estimates put the increase in spending at over €100bn per year, or 6% of GDP.

Italy is not a profligate country. It has run a primary budget surplus since 1992 and only has overall budget deficits due to the interest charges on its extremely large public debts – currently around 130% of GDP. Much of that debt accrued in the 1970s and 1980s as Italy raised funds to develop its welfare state and to invest in the country’s poorer and more agricultural south through the Cassa per il Mezzogiorno programme. Interest rates also rose sharply in the 1980s as the Bank of Italy clamped down on high inflation, raising the debt burden further.

Italy's debt overhang goes back to the 1970s

There are two short-to-medium term problems with the new government’s fiscal plans, the first exists irrespective of whether one believes bigger deficits would lead to the growth and additional tax revenues that would make the new debt sustainable. But both problems potentially lead to conflict between Italy and Europe’s creditor nations such as Germany and the Netherlands.

The first issue is both legal and political. Under the EU’s Fiscal Compact, countries cannot run a budget deficit greater than 3% of GDP, and if they insist on doing so they forfeit the right to assistance from the European Stability Mechanism in times of crisis. Being told by Europe that Italy cannot implement its economic policies is unlikely to reduce populist feeling in the country. Lega’s Matteo Salvini recently said that Italy will not be “slaves of Brussels or Berlin”, while 5-Star’s leader Luigi Di Maio suggested that he will go to “European tables” to fund his spending plans. That means either ignoring or revoking the Fiscal Compact.

The second issue is practical. Running large deficits means issuing quantities of bonds into the market at a time when the central bank is not an active player on the demand side and when interest rates are rising. Italy then would become exposed to significant political risk that could sharply push up yields further and thus the cost of borrowing. That in turn makes servicing Italy’s enormous debt pile even harder and could create centrifugal forces that make the state’s position in the euro area unsustainable. It is the feared ‘debt-crisis’ scenario.

This second issue assumes that markets believe that more state spending would not boost growth, and thus cut the debt-to-GDP ratio in the long-term; that is open for debate. But it also assumes that there are no meaningful political reforms in the euro area. Meaningful reforms include either significant moves to share risk across the region, such as introducing a Eurobond or a “safe European asset” that is backed by all euro area states; or agreeing to a banking union that consists of universal deposit insurance and a fiscal backstop for failed banks. In short, it assumes that Germany and other creditor states in Northern Europe do not agree to any form of risk sharing that ranges from debt guarantees to fully-fledged fiscal transfers.

Northern Europe and particularly Germany remain resistant. Last month, over 150 ordo-liberal German economists warned in a public letter against what they called a “debt union,” which would mean German taxpayers implicitly supporting other states. Chancellor Angela Merkel wants only limited reforms, including a European Monetary Fund that restructures debt and gives loaned assistance only if there are Eurozone-wide systemic risks and recipient countries implement structural reforms. This means exposing investors in troubled states’ bonds to haircuts and lengthened maturities during times of stress.

Unfortunately the German proposals, supported by the Netherlands and Austria, as they stand serve only to crystallise all of the problems that arose from the euro crisis of 2011-15. Merkel’s debt restructuring plan would weaken private sector confidence in peripheral sovereign bonds and reopen the possibility of self-fulfilling fiscal crises. It enacts punishing and self-defeating austerity regimes on troubled debtors, and strengthens the position of German Bunds as a safe asset. Italy will want a bolder approach, and they are likely to push for that ahead of the next EU summit on June 19th. France too will expect bigger concessions after implementing domestic reforms in labour markets and public spending as a quid-pro-quo for more economic integration.

The risk of a future Italian debt crisis also assumes that the ECB will not continue to backstop Italy’s sovereign bonds. This happens by default if the bank eventually moves into a phase of shrinking its balance sheet, but if the next governor of the bank, who takes office in October 2019, takes a more hawkish point of view, as is the preference of the German government, support for Southern European sovereign bonds in a future crisis scenario may not be there. Considering that it was Mario Draghi’s commitment in 2012 to do “whatever it takes” to contain the last crisis, a reversal of that commitment would create clear dangers.

We therefore face the possibility that the political ambitions of Italy’s new government could be thwarted by other countries and the European institutions. The question then becomes whether the populist government could credibly threaten to leave the euro and throw Europe into turmoil to extract concessions from the other countries. The answer is probably ‘no’ as euro-exit would decimate the Italian middle class. However, the systemic importance of Italy in the euro area and the recent shock of Brexit should focus policymakers.

Events in Europe in the last month show that there are still significant tensions between member states that cannot be solved by a short-term burst in economic growth across the region. Yet as that growth starts to slow and the ECB tightens policy, conditions will not be more favourable than they are today to agree the necessary reforms.

What is needed is a greater sense of pan-European solidarity in which your typical German Bavarian thinks of the concerns of the Italian Neapolitan with the same empathy with which she considers the problems of her immediate compatriots. That’s a multi-generational project.  In the absence of that, Europe will continue to evolve through crisis, yet always carrying with it the tail risk of breakup. Political risk in the region has clearly not gone away.

How will Brexit affect family offices?

There has been much concern about the effect of Brexit on the UK’s financial services industry and the position of the City of London. Both Paris and Frankfurt have been seeking to attract people and business from London post-Brexit. European regulators have warned of restricted access to the EU if Britain leaves the single market, as it is likely to do.

One would expect that the dire warnings about the City’s future would cause a fall in business activity ahead of the UK’s exit, but that does not appear to be happening. Last year, cross-border lending by UK-based banks significantly increased for the first time since 2014. Foreign claims by the UK banking sector rose by $300bn last year to $5.1trillion, the biggest one-year increase since 2007 (see chart). The UK’s foreign banking exposure is about the same size as France and Germany’s combined. The upswing in global activity has played a part, but that only serves to underpin a broader point about London’s resilience as a venue for finance beyond Europe.

Since the Brexit referendum in 2016, London has maintained its position as the world’s premier centre for financial services, ahead of New York, Hong Kong and Singapore. It remains the case that London provides not just very deep capital markets, but a trusted legal structure; a whole range of ancillary services, covering insurance, tax and business consultancy; and world-beating cultural amenities.

There are strategic threats to the financial services industry of many large cities. An incompetently arranged Brexit is of course one only for London, but the rise of FinTech and the trend of large institutions spreading out their operations beyond the big cities also provide challenges.

What does this all mean for family offices?  Whilst genuine family offices provide a broad range of financial and non-financial services, the impact of Brexit would only have the potential to affect cross-border financial services such as investment management, capital raising and private equity transactions. Many of these services in the UK operate outside the scope of European regulation and will remain so after Brexit. The UK will be an attractive place for European families who wish to base some or all of their operations outside of Europe and benefit from any regulatory divergence that the UK makes post-Brexit.

There have been worries over whether the lack of so-called passporting rights for UK firms to operate in Europe post-Brexit and restrictions on the delegation of European business to the UK could harm business with EU citizens. However, in recent weeks, Brussels has begun to recognise that any serious trade restrictions would hit both sides if they were effective, or could be nullified by new UK regulatory and tax laws that create strong incentives for European firms and clients to relocate.

One particular area of the industry which is booming is private equity. The total amount spent by private equity firms on new buyouts in Europe hit €90.2bn last year, a rise of 50%. Much of this was driven by the UK, where total deal value almost doubled from €14.7bn last year to €27.1bn this year.

Aspects of the UK private equity industry fall under the regulatory auspices of the FCA and with international investors frequently participating in such investments it is important to consider the impact any change in passporting rights might bring.

Interestingly, however, the vast majority of countries where investors reside exempt either the sophisticated, professional and High Net-Worth investor or the private equity industry from regulatory oversight. Single family offices are exempt for regulations from both the UK and EU. UK-based family offices are therefore well placed to facilitate deals, benefitting from high deal flow, deep capital markets and decades of institutional experience.

We cannot be sure yet what the specific outcomes from the Brexit negotiations will be, but whatever they are, the UK will continue to be an attractive place to do business. London has been at the heart of the global economy for three hundred years and has survived all manner of events including the US War of Independence, the French and Russian Revolutions, and the cataclysms of the 20th century. Brexit cannot really be compared to events of this magnitude. Modern family offices, which have been around since the 5th century, will adapt too, always to the benefit of the clients they serve.

Britain can lead the world in green finance

“I care nothing about the line or what is done with the money. If the East India Company choose to throw the money away, it is nothing to us.” This was how a British investor described the opportunity to fund a railway connecting the lush cotton fields of Gujarat to the port-city of Dholera, reported in an edition of Herapath’s Railway Journal in 1851.

Investors in London almost exclusively financed India’s first railways, but knowledge of the opportunities was scarce. All that mattered was that the British Raj guaranteed a 5% return, and if that meant taxing the Indian people when real returns fell short, then so be it.

It’s been some time since London could rely on the hard power of the British Empire to maintain its position as a dominant financial centre. The City today offers a deep pool of capital precisely because it depends on people who have an intimate knowledge of foreign markets and boasts decades of institutional experience. This makes capital cheaper and attracts worldwide business.

That is why last year, the Indian Railways came back to London Stock Exchange to raise $500m in green bonds to fund the electrification of their network and the replacement of their diesel trains.

That the state-backed company issued green bonds is significant. Britain’s trailblazing approach to climate change and London’s role as a financial hub present a golden opportunity for the UK to be a world-leader in financing the transition to low-carbon economies.

Financial instruments that are ‘green’ are those that fund projects that are defined as environmentally sustainable. As states implement the COP21 Paris Agreement to limit global warming to below 2°C, including regulatory actions that restrict high-carbon activities, the demand from governments and corporates for finance to support sustainable investment will grow.

Savers also increasingly care about how their money is used beyond its financial return. According to State Street Global Advisors, a quarter of all professionally managed assets (or $23trn) has an ESG mandate, growing by over 10% last year.

The OECD estimates that $44trn is needed in additional investments until 2050 to put the world on a sustainable footing. The investment opportunities are huge, from funding low-carbon infrastructure in booming African cities such as Lagos, to supporting China’s plans to build a vast renewable electricity grid across Eurasia, powering its Belt and Road project.

Low carbon investment more than pays for itself in the long-run through fuel savings but the infrastructure requires more up-front capital than dirty alternatives. Providing capital efficiently therefore matters.

London’s opportunity is to arrange and structure global green investments, and to manage assets with green mandates. The world needs deep, liquid, information-rich and well-regulated capital markets for green investments. Global investors want green financial products they can trust.

While Brexit threatens to weaken London’s lucrative role in underwriting European debt, it is unlikely to preclude steps to make the City attractive for emerging markets.

The Government’s Green Finance Taskforce recently presented a range of proposals that would advance London’s position. These include leading on regulatory standards in sustainable finance and on the corporate disclosure of climate risks and opportunities, as well as supporting research into the new field of green finance.

By providing these services, London can attract new business while keeping capital costs low for issuers, quickening the green transition.

The UK also needs to promote green finance at home. Britain has led the world in cutting emissions, down 43% on 1990, but it needs to go further. The next steps in decarbonisation, which include improvements in electricity storage and the development of hydrogen fuels for industry, will be harder to achieve and require more concerted support from the state.

The Green Finance Taskforce recommends that the government issue its own sovereign green bond, but it could go further.

In support of its Industrial Strategy, the government should set up a national development bank to allocate the proceeds of multiple green bond issuances, supporting research, the development of early-stage technologies, and emerging companies. It would create further opportunities for private capital to support.

Bank of England Governor Mark Carney last week spoke about the risks to financial stability posed by a delayed transition to sustainable economies. There is a case for reviewing the Bank’s mandate to allow it to favour green bonds in its asset purchasing programme. Boosting the availability of green finance through the central bank looks prudent.

The government through its Brexit strategy wants a Global Britain. Its 25-Year Environmental Plan aims for a green Britain, too. Green finance connects the two. It offers a new role for the nation that introduced the world to the industrial method and whose imperial legacy still touches billions of people.

Green finance presents an opportunity for the London and the wider UK to lead, at home and abroad, on the biggest issue facing our shared home. It’s time to seize it.

Fine Wine, Low Volatility

By Rodney Birrell, Founding Director of The Wine Investment Fund

The dramatic return of market volatility to equity markets in February 2018 was felt across the world. The VIX index (Wall Street’s “fear gauge”) had its greatest percentage jump on record, as stock markets in the US, Europe and Asia suddenly dropped. Concerns over returning inflation is putting pressure on interest rates and as a result, investors are turning to alternative assets as a means of financial diversification.

The fine wine market is characterised by relatively low volatility (annualised volatility of 10.2% – see chart, Liv-ex Investables), and even though precious metals such as gold (15.9%) have traditionally been considered safe haven assets, volatility within this asset class limits its ability to be considered as a store-of-value. Other commodities such as oil have also shown high volatility. The FTSE has an annualised volatility of 14.1%.

Stability of fine wine is a result of the unique features of this physical asset. Using The Wine Investment Fund’s definition of investment grade wine, the total market size is some £6bn with annual inflows (new production) and outflows (consumption) of around £1 billion. Therefore, the stock of fine wine is not only relatively constant, but is appreciated all over the world and sought after by a growing number of consumers regardless of economic and social conditions – a truly global market.

As a physical asset, wine has a defined inherent value and may therefore be used as a hedge against inflation. Similarly, to gold, fine wine is also an incredibly stable asset, with quality improving rather than depreciating over time as it matures, unlike other alternative investments. Uniquely, the quantity of any vintage decreases naturally, through consumption, as its quality improves as the wine matures and demand therefore increases.

Fine wine is also uncorrelated with other mainstream investment markets such as equities. Shocks in these markets have relatively small – if any – impact on fine wine prices in normal market conditions. For example, with the volatility seen in equities at the start of February 2018, the daily Liv-ex 50 index has remained within a 0.5% range (currently down 0.1% (at 27/02/2018) since the end of January), while the FTSE is currently down 3.04% since the start of the month (at 27/02/2018). This low volatility can also be seen historically using the longest available reliable index, the Liv-ex Investables – see graph.

Long term low volatility and high returns in the fine wine market can also be seen in the market’s risk-adjusted returns (see Sharpe ratio chart).

The introduction of centralised exchanges (such as Liv-ex in 2000) and the use of technology has markedly improved market liquidity and transparency. This has created a sophisticated space for fine wine as an alternative investable asset. Enhanced price discovery and security has allowed the market to develop an infrastructure similar to that of mainstream investment markets such as equities, with a success not yet seen in other collectibles such as art, cars and jewellrey. This has led to dramatic improvements in liquidity (the average market spread of the Liv-ex 50 index – Bordeaux First Growths – is approximately 3.5%) and a stable market environment.

As a store of value fine wine is also much more accessible than other alternative investments/collectibles such as classic cars. There is a wide range of investment grade wines available in the market. The Wine Investment Fund’s universe from which it stock picks the wines held in its portfolios (and which satisfies the Fund’s strict liquidity and quality criteria), amounts to 350 individual wines, with an average price per case of £3,000 per 12x75cl. In contrast, the average price of the 50 classic car models which comprise the HAGI Top index is £619,000 – not exactly within the range of most investors. Furthermore, investors may efficiently gain access to the wine market (i.e. invest in a well-diversified portfolio) through funds such as The Wine Investment Fund, the oldest publicly available wine fund launched in 2003, where the minimum subscription is £10,000.

Given the low volatility, the low correlation, the high liquidity and the high returns, all on a relative basis compared to other asset classes, an investment in wine becomes a must have for investors looking to establish or to maintain a well-balanced investment portfolio.

Could wages in the US remain subdued?

The consensus view in markets is that the United States is in the late stage of its economy cycle, that it is very close to full employment and that inflation will accelerate this year. On the back of this, many expect that the Federal Reserve – anticipating an overheating economy – will raise interest rates multiple times this year and scale back their asset purchases.

But what if this view is wrong? While we do see signs that indicate inflationary pressures in the US–from lagged PMI trends and capacity utilisation figures – we have repeatedly pointed out that unemployment is a misleading indicator of tightness in the US labour market. This is because the measure is blind to the large volumes of people who left the labour force after the Great Recession of 2007-9 and who are now returning. Official unemployment is a measure for only those people who are in the labour force at any given point in time but do not have a job.

This is the position that Martin Sandbu at the Financial Times (£) takes yesterday, and it can best be illustrated in the chart below.

RISING

Sandbu’s basic idea is that it is possible for the US economy to continue hiring people but for wages to remain muted as more people return to the labour market. We can see in the chart above that labour force participation – the proportion in the population of 25-54 year olds which takes part in the jobs market – is still well below its 1990s-peak, while the employment rate – the proportion of the population that has a job – is below its cyclical peaks in 2001 and 2007. The message, Sandbu concludes, is that there is still spare capacity in the US economy even though unemployment is low; and wage (and price) inflation is subdued because both employment and labour force participation are rising.

How likely is this? There is reason for doubt. Unemployment among 25-54 year-olds as a proportion of the population, implied by the gap between labour force participation and the employment rate in the chart, is also near the cyclical lows of 2001 and 2007. This is not the official measure of unemployment, which measures the proportion of the labour force that is unemployed, as opposed to the proportion of the population. However, official unemployment is also at similar cyclical lows. In both 2001 and 2007 for both measures, unemployment turned upwards within twelve months of peaking. This behaviour can be seen in the chart below at the peak of almost every economic cycle in the US since 1948. The only exceptions are in the late 1950s and late 1960s, when unemployment held steady as the economy added new jobs.

UENMEP

The question then is: which is the better cyclical predictor for labour market tightness – employment or unemployment? While Sandbu’s argument for the employment rate is plausible, it implicitly assumes that the damage wrought by the Great Recession can be largely if not fully unwound. On that point, we are sceptical.

There is evidence that during recessions, firms are more likely not just to fire workers but replace them with technology. Technological change has made large numbers of middle-aged Blue Collar men redundant. 90% of jobs in clothing manufacturing and 40% of jobs in electronics in the US have disappeared since 1990. Indeed, the labour force participation rate itself has been trending down since 2000. These jobs are not coming back and for many of the workers who are affected it is not possible technically or mentally to reskill. The scale of the opioid crisis points to the despair that many of these people feel with regards to their situation.

We don’t know what the scale of the damage has been, but there is good reason to believe that the labour force will not reach the size it did in the late 1990s. This doesn’t mean that labour force participation cannot continue rising in the short-term, delaying inflationary pressures; or that we should not pay attention to other measures of labour market tightness such as employment. But Sandbu’s implicit suggestion that, because employment remains low compared to the last 20 years, the US is necessarily still far from full employment is too easy. It is possible that the US economy has exhausted the gains from increased labour force participation, meaning that employment cannot continue to rise without pushing down unemployment, which is at cyclical lows. And this would most likely be inflationary.

We still therefore expect wage and price inflation to pick up this year as the US labour market tightens, but we would not be surprised if the process takes a bit longer than it does under the consensus view, with signs manifesting only during H2 2018. The Trump Administration’s fiscal stimulus program will, however, act only to hasten inflation’s arrival.

Positive Territory for the Third Consecutive Year for Fine Wine

By Rodney Birrell, Founding Director of The Wine Investment Fund

The fine wine market ended 2017 in positive territory for the third consecutive year with the Liv-ex 100 index, the industry leading benchmark, closing +5.66% and the Liv-ex Investables index gaining a similar 5.68%. It was also a year of records on Liv-ex, the fine wine exchange. Market exposure, the value of all live bids and offers, reached £48m and the bid-to-offer ratio remained above 1 throughout the year; for Bordeaux wines the ratio now stands at 1.8 with almost twice as much value on the buy-side (a bid:offer ratio of 0.5 or higher has historically indicated an upward trend in the market or at least acted as a signal for price stability). Trade on Liv-ex also broadened in 2017 with over 8000 active markets and more merchants than ever before trading on the exchange. The returning demand of traditional markets such as the USA and Asia has continued to be driven by weakness of GBP Sterling relative to the US Dollar and Euro (important because the secondary market for investment grade wines is GBP denominated) and the ever-growing demand for the world’s best wines. UK merchant BI Wines and Spirits “have seen a continued increase in volume sales of physical vintages, especially of Bordeaux, particularly to Asia” in 2017.

Increased attendance (up 2.3% on 2016) at the 2017 Hong Kong International Wine & Spirits Fair and the newly introduced preferential measures for wine imports from Hong Kong into mainland China (an increase in the number of ports available, expediting clearance improvements and developments in the accounting of duty, recognising the growth in wine imports to China) are positive signs of stable demand in the Far-East. In addition, the European Union and Japan have reached agreement on a free-trade deal which will eliminate tariffs on imports of EU goods, including wine, to Japan. The country is already one of the top 5 markets for EU wine in general and Bordeaux in particular and any increase in demand could have significant positive effects on prices. Demand from the Far-East has not just been for the purchase of fine wines, but also for the purchase of chateaux, with over 100 properties in Bordeaux now under Asian ownership, suggesting a continuing commitment to the region.

Results from the main auction houses throughout 2017 (Sotheby’s, Christie’s and Bonham’s) have repeatedly been above the high estimates and global demand has been a prominent feature: the Sotheby’s (sales of $64m in 2017) sale in New York in December reported strong bidding from North American (50% of sales) and Asian buyers (45%) and First Growth Bordeaux were sold at 20% over the high estimate. Luxury goods group LVMH (owners of chateaux Cheval Blanc and d’Yquem) reported growth in revenue and profits in its Wines & Spirits division, including “very strong” sales in the US and China. This suggests that demand for the most prestigious drinks brands continues to grow amongst the world’s wealthiest. These are also strong indicators of traditional collectors having returned to the market in 2017.

The Knight Frank Luxury Investment index, which tracks the price growth in the major categories of collectables found that wine has replaced cars as the top collectables, thanks to the performance of French wines. Compiled by Wine Owners, a business and collector trading platform, it reported “Wine’s performance was driven by exceptionally strong growth in key areas across the world and in particular the resurgence of the top Bordeaux chateaux, which form the backbone of most investment cellars”.

Despite a successful en-primeur (the top 20 merchants sold approximately £85m – up 46% on 2016 – with US wine merchant JJ Buckley reporting their largest ever campaign), Bordeaux producers have continually been reported to be holding back the majority of production and tightened supply of new vintages. For example, the 2016 vintage was larger in volume than 2015, but only a similar number of cases have ended up in the UK. This has driven demand across a range of physical vintages. Paul Pong of Hong Kong based merchant Altaya Wines found difficulties sourcing volume and believes “chateaux are releasing little to no supply for their first tranche”. The tightening of supply and rejuvenated demand emphasises the markets low volatility and we believe this will continue to put upward pressure on pricing. Optimism surrounding the 2015/16 vintages and a broadening market make it an attractive time to invest in fine wine and it offers an important opportunity to diversify into an asset-backed market and a hedge against returning inflation.

Inflationary pressures in Europe are the hidden danger

Much has been made of how the recent wage data coming from the US was the cause of the correction we saw in asset markets last week. It suggested that the Phillips curve may finally be asserting itself at a time when producer and commodity prices have been rising and the temporary factors cited by the Federal Reserve as holding inflation back are easing.

However, a bigger risk is that inflationary pressures are building in the euro area. The ECB has engineered a huge export of capital from Europe to the United States with its programme of asset purchases since 2016. The ECB’s bond buying programme pushed European yields down and encouraged investors to ‘search for yield’ in relatively more mature US markets that offered higher returns.

Markets got jittery in January after the release of the minutes of the ECB’s Governing Council most recent meeting, indicating that inflation may come through sooner than expected and that the central bank was willing to change its language with regard to its future policies. Investors up until then more or less believed Mario Draghi’s commitment to easy policy for as long as necessary to support the euro area’s recovery and the convergence of inflation towards the bank’s 2.0% target. Very little activity on rates is priced in.

However, there are good reasons to believe that inflation will pick up this year in Europe. Since 2014, capacity utilisation, a measure of the degree to which firms are using their resources, has been creeping up. Part of this reflected the low level of capital expenditure in the bloc and weak bank lending. The acceleration in EZ growth in 2017 caught a lot of manufacturers by surprise, with many increasing capex spending. Imports into the euro area in the year to November 2017 grew by over 7%, with the largest increases in import volumes in machinery from capital goods exporters such as China and South Korea, as well as in energy from Russia.

Nevertheless, capacity remains constrained and inflation is currently much lower than it should be as suggested by the level of utilisation (see chart below). It certainly has the potential to break through the 2% target-level within the next 12 months.

The other indicator that points to a pick-up in inflation is the level of unemployment. It is easy to be deceived by the European jobs market. In most Anglo-Saxon countries, unemployment typically has to fall below 5% before signs of price pressures emerge.

Anglo-Saxon economies tend to have more flexible labour markets that support people who have generalist skills. This means firms tend to report shortages when most people who want a job already have one.

In continental Europe, employment is typically more exclusive. To break into many parts of the French, Italian and German labour market, workers typically need to have specialist skills that cannot be easily transferred to other occupations and require years of training to acquire. Further, the costs of employing workers are typically higher due to taxes and regulation, which encourage firms to substitute workers for machines. Higher rates of unionisation can protect insiders at the expense of outsiders. And more recently, the scale and length of the euro crisis have increased the long-term unemployment of young people. All these factors mean that firms across the EZ are reporting skill shortages despite headline figures of unemployment of around 8.5%.

As the chart below shows, there is a relatively tight relationship between trends in HICP CPI inflation, which the ECB targets through its policies, and the level of unemployment six months prior. It shows that inflation starts to accelerate when unemployment falls below 8.5%, roughly where it is today. It also suggests that based on the steady reductions in unemployment since 2013, inflation is likely to pick up later this year. It is not out of the question that it could break through the ECB’s inflation target.

Together then, both capacity utilisation and unemployment figures point to upward price pressures that are unlikely to be offset by the downward pressures of a stronger euro on import prices. Add to that the strong EZ-wide PMI data and we think there is a strong case for a change in the ECB’s stance in the second half of this year.

Last week’s correction was healthy for equity markets which looked overstretched. But it did little to change the extraordinary fact that more than 15% of bonds on global markets trade with negative interest rates, according to Deutsche Bank. As central banks move from quantitative easing to quantitative tightening in the second half of 2018, that situation will have to change, which would at the very least create a more unstable and volatile market environment as both bonds and equities adjust to their fair values.

Donald Trump’s protectionism depends on the dollar

Donald Trump put ‘America First’ front and centre of his pitch to business elites at the World Economic Forum in Davos last week. WEF is a club for business leaders, financiers and politicians who mostly share a suspicion of nationalism and a belief that globalisation is good. But Mr. Trump, surely knowing this, went to sell his country.

“America is open for business and we are competitive once again.” He praised his administration’s efforts in cutting taxes, slashing regulations and renegotiating trade agreements. The results, he boasted, were billions of dollars of announced investments in the United States.

However, competitiveness in international markets can also arise from a cheap currency. The US President didn’t mention this anywhere in his speech, but one had the impression that if his other policy proposals fall flat, the option of pushing down the dollar would be the last resort in his fight against so-called unfair trade.

At face value it seems that movements in the US trade balance have had little to do with the real effective exchange rate (REER) in recent times, as the chart below shows. To improve the fit of the two series, we would need to lag the real exchange rate by three years, but it’s implausible that it takes that long for businesses to react to changes in the real exchange rate.

There will never be a perfect relationship between REER and the trade balance, especially the US trade balance, for a number of reasons: because not all trade is price-sensitive; because the dollar is a safe-haven currency and the world’s reserve currency of choice; because many commodity contracts are priced and settled in dollars; and because speculation allows investors to take bets on the future path of national economies.

However, it remains the case that REER is the variable that ‘co-moves’ most closely with the trade balance. Sometimes the REER responds to the trade balance, driven by international capital flows and demand shocks; and other times it’s the trade balance that responds to changes in the REER. That said, the discrepancies of the 2000s – during which the dollar consistently fell but trade deficits grew – look rather large and need some explanation.

The 1990s saw the US boom relative to the rest of the world, with growth averaging close to 4% under Bill Clinton. It was these fundamentals that led to the dollar appreciating strongly during the decade as foreign capital flowed in, a process that accelerated immediately after the Asian Financial Crisis in 1999. The Clinton Administration also favoured a strong dollar because it kept inflation and interest rates low and put pressure on domestic producers to improve their competitiveness through investment. But it also caused the trade deficit to rise sharply.

While the dollar fell against most DM currencies after the US fell into recession in 2002, it continued to rise against currencies of key emerging economies which represented around half of US trade deficit in goods at the time. The dollar continued to rise against the Mexican Peso until 2007 and remained flat against the Chinese Renminbi until 2005, causing the trade deficit to keep rising. Mexico and China alone accounted for over 40% of America’s 2006 trade deficit.

It was largely China’s dollar-renminbi peg between 1995 and 2005 that distorted the relationship between REER and the US trade deficit after 2002. Large-scale capital export from China to the US also maintained a distended trade deficit until 2008.

Accusations of currency manipulation by the United States’ trading partners pre-date Trump by almost twenty years. In 1988, the US Congress passed the Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act, which called for more action to be taken against nations which were identified as fixing their currency to steal an advantage. It was only in 2005, ten years after China had begun holding the renminbi at 8.28 yuan to the dollar, that Congress’s threat of tariffs against China – on the grounds that the peg turbo-charged the US trade deficit by preventing the renminbi from rising – caused the country to abandon the policy.

In the immediate aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis, China halted its ‘managed appreciation’ and resumed its dollar peg at 6.83 yuan to the dollar for over two years, which led to new accusations of currency manipulation as the US trade balance started to tick up again.

Since the end of 2011, the dollar has rallied, benefitting from the combined effect of being the first major economy to recover from the GFC and, more latterly, being the main recipient of the ‘search for yield’ process that has followed loose monetary policies around the world. But as of yet, the trade deficit has yet to deteriorate further, although the most recent figures suggest it is rising.

Last year, the dollar lost close to 10% of its value on a trade-weighted basis and it is now common to hear talk of the dollar as now being ‘weak’. But this is not so. By recent standards, the dollar is still relatively strong, and on a short-term basis there is scope for capital repatriation from the Trump tax reforms to push the dollar up this year.

Fundamentals, however, suggest that unless the dollar falls over the medium run, and there is good reason to think it will (the return of Europe, the strength of EMs, normalisation in policy outside the US), the trade deficit should rise, and this creates a source of political risk from Donald Trump.

Trump cares about the trade deficit. He thinks that a large deficit means that the US is somehow losing money. It is also true that his core voters – blue collar, manufacturing workers – struggle with a strong dollar. If his tax and regulatory reforms fail to bear fruit for the people that he claims to represent – with firms using the benefits of depreciation expensing to fund stock buybacks rather than capital investment – we would not be surprised if this unpredictable President turns to more drastic action on currency and trade restrictions, including managed interventions and tariffs. And that would create all kinds of problems for businesses that use international supply chains, central banks that have independent mandates and – in extremis – whole economies that depend on the rules-based international trading system.